Brexit: A midsummer’s night’s ‘mare


Anton Muscatelli

Economist Professor Anton Muscatelli, Principal of the University of Glasgow, writing in a personal capacity and the views expressed do not reflect those of Policy Scotland or the University of Glasgow.  

 

The mixture of fantasy and reality on which the Leave campaign is basing its arguments might lack the brilliance and wit of Shakespeare’s comedy, but it does have the potential to do serious harm to the UK economy.

 

One reason why the arguments for Brexit are so beguiling is that it’s easy to imagine an alternative world where some of the current laws of economics or politics don’t apply. Campaigners for Leave have tried to conjure a fantasy world in which after leaving the EU, the UK has an opportunity to design its own economic environment, with its ideal configuration of free trade, limited labour mobility, less regulation, and foreign investment. A sovereign nation which will dominate post-Brexit negotiations with our former EU partners and the rest of the world. With the odd unicorn and fairy thrown in for good measure.

 

Reality looks a little bit different. We have to distinguish carefully between sovereignty and power, and we need to understand the options the UK has in terms of trade relationships.

 

Calculating the impact of an EU exit is complex. All the possible alternative trade regimes which might apply to the UK have to be modelled, including the extent of labour mobility and migration; foreign direct investment our contribution to the EU budget; regulation and productivity growth. All these variables are inter-related and cannot be chosen independently as the Brexit campaigners would wish to argue.

 

The Treasury has produced one of the most complete attempts to model these inter-relationships and analyse the long-term implications which take account of the impact of trade on FDI and productivity. The message is stark. UK GDP would be between -3.8% and -7.5% lower depending on whether the UK strikes a Norway-type trade agreement or a bilateral (Canada, Turkey, Switzerland) agreement, or if we simply adopt WTO rules.

 

Those advocating Brexit criticise these figures, but their own estimates rely on scenarios which are less comprehensive and over-estimate the gains from regulatory reform, reduced contributions to the EU budget, or the reduction in trade diversion from leaving the EU trade block.  They  focus on the gains from reduced protectionism and more open trade. and play up the UK’s net contribution to the EU which in recent years has been around £9bn.

 

These Brexit net-gain scenarios are unpersuasive because they identify the benefits from leaving but not the additional costs.

 

The improving trade balance argument is that our agricultural and manufacturing imports would be cheaper outside the EU. But this ‘ignores the reality that if the UK reduced higher tariffs in dairy or meat imports this would hit our farming communities. Re-directing our exports to other parts of the world is also problematic. In 2014, 45% of our total exports went to the EU. More significantly, 63% of our goods exports  are linked to our EU membership.  We know that in trade, geography matters: regardless of trade agreements countries are more likely to trade with those closest to them. Our total trade costs with the EU have fallen by 20% in the last 15 years. By contrast, the costs of trading with the rest of the OECD and the emerging economies have hardly changed.

 

More worryingly non-tariff barriers might actually increase following Brexit. These may apply to trade in goods but also to services where the UK is a net exporter. There is already talk of UK-based financial services institutions having to move to Frankfurt, Amsterdam or Luxembourg. Other service companies may move, worried about potential ‘home-bias’ within the EU following Brexit.

 

Brexit advocates tell us that we would be able to negotiate a strong trade deal with the EU. The Germans want to sell us their cars and the French their wine and cheese. Life in reality looks less rosy than these clichés suggest. UK exports to the EU are 12% of our GDP. Germany and France’s exports to the UK are 3% and 2% of their GDP. Not all of the EU countries run trade surpluses with the UK and would be clamouring for a deal. Ireland and the Netherlands would be the only EU countries that would be seriously harmed by Britain leaving.

 

It’s likely that any EU trade deal following Brexit would look something like this: First, the UK would have to agree on full labour mobility and access to benefits, without any of the emergency brakes which the UK government has negotiated. Second, it would need to contribute to the EU budget, at levels similar to what we currently contribute. Norway contributes about 17% less per capita than the UK. There would be no fiscal windfall. Third, we would have to adopt all current EU regulations, and we might be subject to harmonisation of labour markets.

 

Of course free-market Brexiteers might eschew such a deal in favour of a WTO-based solution. The problem with this is that we would become a brutal free-market island. The UK would become a very different economy and society. The loss of tax revenues highlighted by the Treasury would mean expenditure cuts which imply dismantling major elements of our welfare state, including the NHS. Paradoxically in pursuing aggressive external trade we would have to further open up our borders to migration to bring the skills which our demographic trends require. We may also have to abandon some of the social protection on labour markets.

 

In the real world of economics and politics unlike the fantasy world of Brexit you get to choose some of the economic variables but not all of them. If you want free trade in the EU you have to accept contributing to the EU budget and free mobility of labour. If you choose the WTO world you have to accept that global markets determine the size of your welfare state and your regulatory environment.